When it comes to innovations in the face of global pandemics, business as usual for our innovation system is unlikely to apply. There are strong pressures to make it freely available, and in the process, push down the return to any R&D that has been conducted
Illustration: Courtesy Rotman
One key lesson from the global pandemic crisis is that funding for medical research is woefully inadequate. We must do better.
In the early days of the global pandemic lockdown that saw so many of us working from home, my thoughts turned to how we can innovate our way out of this and future crises. The movie Mission Impossible 2 soon came to mind. Released in 2000, the antagonist is an Australian-based biotech company (Biocyte Pharmaceuticals, if you must know) with a rather unique commercialization plan. It has developed a virus, Chimera, that could start a very bad pandemic. It lies dormant for 20 hours before destroying the carrier’s red blood cells. One plan might have been threatening to release the virus and be paid not to do so. But the folks at Biocyte go one step further. They plan to release the virus itself because they have also developed the cure. And, get this, they hold the patent on it.
Suffice it to say, I suspect some venture capitalists would call this one ‘fundable’. The movie’s plot involves the chase to stop the virus from being released but also to secure the cure in case it is. But I wonder, did they have to do that? The plan was to release the virus and then charge for the cure. Drugs normally, once made available, are easy to copy and so have patents. The plan here was to use the patent to extort world governments to pay up much of their global wealth.
But herein lies the problem: the patent is granted by those governments. Surely in this situation, they would just invalidate the patent and take the cure? The point is that when it comes to innovations in the face of global pandemics, business as usual for our innovation system is unlikely to apply. The reason is that once an innovation has been created, there are strong pressures to make it freely available, and in the process, push down the return to any R&D that has been conducted. Anticipating this, businesses may not invest in R&D in the first place.
This is not a hypothetical situation. As economists Michael Kremer and Heidi Williams, professors at Harvard and Stanford, respectively, write in their 2010 article “Incentivizing Innovation†(published in Innovation Policy and the Economy): Such concerns are likely very salient to firms. For example, after Senator Paula Hawkins (R-FL) asked a major vaccine manufacturer how it could justify charging nearly three times as much to the U.S. government for vaccines as to foreign countries, U.S. manufacturers stopped submitting bids to UNICEF to supply vaccines...When President Bill Clinton announced his plan to immunize all children against a standard list of diseases in 1993, he said, “I cannot believe that anyone seriously believes that America should manufacture vaccines for the world, sell them cheaper in foreign countries, and immunize fewer kids as a percentage of the population than any nation in this hemisphere but Bolivia and Haitiâ€... In the face of such statements, potential risks facing firms seem real.
[This article has been reprinted, with permission, from Rotman Management, the magazine of the University of Toronto's Rotman School of Management]